This shows you the differences between two versions of the page.
fair_trade_for_all [2010/07/02 13:05] dan |
fair_trade_for_all [2019/11/08 10:39] |
||
---|---|---|---|
Line 1: | Line 1: | ||
- | **[[wp> | ||
- | ====== Introduction ====== | ||
- | |||
- | ===== Recent WTO History ===== | ||
- | |||
- | The Uruguay Round completed in 1994, establishing the [[wp> | ||
- | |||
- | That consensus was formally announced at the next ministerial conference in Doha in 2001 in the form of the [[wp> | ||
- | * trade and investment | ||
- | * competition policy | ||
- | * transparency in government procurement, | ||
- | * trade facilitation. | ||
- | |||
- | Developing countries, wary of entering another bad agreement after the failures of Doha, have blocked progress on developed countries' | ||
- | |||
- | ===== Outline of the Book ===== | ||
- | |||
- | This book attempts to outline what a true agenda for a development round should contain, based on a review of theoretical and empirical economics. | ||
- | |||
- | > Trade liberalisation is supposed to deliver gains as resources are transferred from protected sectors in which a country does not have comparative advantage, to those sectors where it is more efficient and where it can export more successfully. | ||
- | |||
- | ====== Trade Can Be Good for Development ====== | ||
- | |||
- | The proposition that international trade is welfare-enhancing is one of the most established in economics, dating at least to Adam Smith (1776) and David Ricardo (1816). | ||
- | |||
- | However, whilst economics textbooks discuss the difference between the binary states of autarky (no trade) and free trade, real countries have had to make much more subtle choices between an infinite number of slightly varying trade regimes representing different levels of overall liberalisation. | ||
- | |||
- | Almost every country retains some form of tariff restriction, | ||
- | |||
- | > Some of the developed countries that have been the most ardent advocates of trade liberalisation have been somewhat duplicitous in their advocacy. | ||
- | |||
- | A particular twist of economic theory that has been used by the developed countries is to pretend that unilateral liberalisation by developing countries in itself is good, regardless of whether its trading partners are also undergoing liberalisation relevant to its export interests. | ||
- | |||
- | The next section will examine the assertion that trade is good for welfare and good for growth with reference to a few country histories. | ||
- | |||
- | ===== East Asia (export-orientation) ===== | ||
- | |||
- | The modern East Asian growth phenomenon began with Japan in the immediate post-war period, growing to be the second-largest global economy within a few decades. | ||
- | |||
- | East Asia successfully refuted two classic propositions of development, | ||
- | * inequality is not necessary to growth (Lewis (1955) had argued that inequality was required for the high savings necessary for growth) | ||
- | * inequality does not need to rise in the early stages of development (as Kuznets had argued (1955)) | ||
- | |||
- | There were important differences between the policy approach of different countries. | ||
- | * FDI: Japan and Korea restricted FDI flows, instead using investment from domestic corporate conglomerates((FDI made up less than 5 per cent of GDP between 1987--92.)), | ||
- | |||
- | They also had much in common: | ||
- | * high rates of investment in physical and human capital | ||
- | * rapid growth in agricultural productivity | ||
- | * declining fertility | ||
- | |||
- | Most controversial has been the role of the state in the East Asian miracle. | ||
- | |||
- | Following orthodoxy: | ||
- | * stability-oriented macroeconomic policy: | ||
- | * responsible monetary and fiscal policy | ||
- | * low inflation | ||
- | * realistic real exchange rate | ||
- | * reliable legal framework | ||
- | * in sum: " | ||
- | |||
- | Whereas, against orthodox opinion: | ||
- | * Japan intervened to cultivate heavy industries: steel, aluminium, automotive and shipbuilding, | ||
- | * subsidised credit to favoured industries | ||
- | * trade policy | ||
- | * protection for infant industries, including protection both from imports and domestic competition | ||
- | * promotion for export-ready industries, including export marketing institutions | ||
- | * in sum: a " | ||
- | |||
- | Laissez-faire economists argue that the latter policies had no effect or were harmful, and that Asian success was a consequence of the former. | ||
- | |||
- | One thing is clear, that the Asian economies were highly successful without a strict adherence to the Washington Consensus and that controversy certainly remains about the effectiveness of different trade and industrial policies, and controls on capital flows in different contexts. | ||
- | |||
- | > In this context it is inappropriate for the world trading system to be implementing rules which circumscribe the ability for developing countries to use both trade and industry policies to promote industrialisation. | ||
- | |||
- | ===== Latin America (import substitution) ===== | ||
- | |||
- | Many Latin American countries were inspired by the experiences of the main belligerents of World War II, who all abandoned free market pretensions in favour of intensive state planning and coordination to achieve the massive increase in output required by the war effort. | ||
- | |||
- | This practical experience was supported by development economists who argued that massive government intervention was required in a 'big push' to benefit from economies of scale and demand from workers in other industries. | ||
- | * raise tariffs on manufactures that could be produced locally (import substitution) | ||
- | * give priority to industrialists importing capital goods in foreign exchange markets | ||
- | |||
- | Obviously, this policy of favouring industries in which the country had no comparative advantage directly contradicts Ricardo' | ||
- | |||
- | > [T]he theory of comparative advantage told South Korea, as it emerged from the Korean War, that it should specialise in rice. But Korea believed that even if it were successful in increasing the productivity of its rice farmers, it would never become a middle- or high-income country if it followed that course. | ||
- | |||
- | Latin American countries grew rapidly in the decades of import substitution (averaging 6 per cent across the region during the 1970s), but then one country after another fell into crisis in the early 1980s. | ||
- | |||
- | The neoliberal conclusion was that Latin America had failed due to its inferior policy: state intervention to support national industries had left them uncompetitive and inefficient, | ||
- | |||
- | The opposing view argues that Latin America' | ||
- | * a demand shock to their exports | ||
- | * a consequent fall in commodity prices and terms of trade shock | ||
- | * an interest rate shock (their debt was denominated in dollars), and | ||
- | * a capital supply shock. | ||
- | |||
- | Consequently, | ||
- | |||
- | > This alternative view suggests that it was Latin America' | ||
- | |||
- | ===== Mexico and NAFTA ===== | ||
- | |||
- | In 1994, Mexico entered the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) with the US and Canada. | ||
- | |||
- | Ten years on, the results have been mixed. | ||
- | * Mexican exports have grown around 10 per cent per year | ||
- | * FDI has increased | ||
- | * NAFTA helped Mexico to recover from the Tequila Crisis of 1994--5 | ||
- | |||
- | However, in many ways NAFTA has failed to live up to its advocates' | ||
- | * growth during the first decade of free trade was slower than during the import-substitution years (before 1980) | ||
- | * average real wages were lower a decade later than on entry into force | ||
- | * some of the most vulnerable groups had been made worse off as subsidised US agricultural commodities depressed domestic Mexican prices | ||
- | * inequality increased | ||
- | * poverty increased | ||
- | * a decade on, Mexico was losing many of the jobs it had gained to China | ||
- | * the manufacturing sector has seen output growth but a reduction in employment | ||
- | |||
- | Three lessons should be taken from the experience: | ||
- | * trade liberalisation alone does not ensure growth, and its impact may be swamped by other factors (eg Mexico' | ||
- | * Mexico' | ||
- | * NAFTA was not really a free trade agreement, as it did not eliminate US agricultural subsidies, enabling the US to export below the cost of production. | ||
- | |||
- | |||
- | ===== Theory: Liberalisation, | ||
- | |||
- | Aside from the traditional argument that trade brings a welfare gain through comparative advantage, there are four further channels through which liberalisation can bring costs and benefits: | ||
- | * the creation of economies of scale through opening foreign markets | ||
- | * reduction of the price of inputs, lowering production costs | ||
- | * increase in competition from foreign firms, and | ||
- | * liberalisation may affect the rate of economic growth. | ||
- | |||
- | Traditional arguments for liberalisation usually focus on welfare rather than growth --- ie the long-run rate of growth will not be affected. | ||
- | |||
- | However, the assumptions which yield the result that free trade is superior to any intermediate range of trade restrictions (Samuelson, 1962) are restrictive and often inapplicable to developing countries. | ||
- | |||
- | The second key assumption is the existence of perfect risk markets. | ||
- | |||
- | > Under quite plausible conditions, one can show that free trade is Pareto-inferior to autarky --- everyone is worse off --- which is just the opposite result to that of the conventional wisdom. ---p26 | ||
- | |||
- | A third assumption is in the effectiveness of the price mechanism. | ||
- | |||
- | Government revenue can also provide a rationale for trade taxes, in certain circumstances. | ||
- | |||
- | Trade liberalisation also affects inequality: there are winners and losers. | ||
- | |||
- | Another type of market failure is based on information externalities. | ||
- | |||
- | > [I]t is no great surprise that low-income countries are not teeming with entrepreneurs engaged in self-discovery. ---Dani Rodrik, 2004, cited p29 | ||
- | |||
- | Perhaps more important than the impact on welfare is liberalisation' | ||
- | * large (export) markets increase returns to R&D | ||
- | * technological spillovers may exist within but not between countries --- then greater specialisation would lead to faster technological advances | ||
- | |||
- | These tend to emphasise the importance of knowledge, learning and human capital, but these are areas that often require extensive government intervention to push an economy towards comparative advantages that can capitalise on this long-term development. | ||
- | |||
- | The infant industry argument states that a new industry requires a period of " | ||
- | |||
- | There are two reasons that this criticism may be flawed. | ||
- | |||
- | > Banks would have to be willing to lend to enable firms to sell below cost, in the hope that by doing so their productivity will increase so much that they will become a viable competitor. | ||
- | |||
- | Secondly, if there are spillovers and some of the gains of learning are captured by rival firms (for instance, if employees leave to set up competitor firms), then the gains to the pioneer firm may not cover the cost of investing in their learning. | ||
- | |||
- | > Once capital market imperfections are taken into account, then protection may be optimal, as Dasgupta and Stiglitz (1980) show. They argue, in particular, that protection may have advantages over other instruments, | ||
- | |||
- | An alternative approach is to create strong intellectual property rights that protect the pioneer firm both from foreign and domestic competition.((Historically, | ||
- | |||
- | ===== Empirical Evidence ===== | ||
- | |||
- | > The economic growth literature has been successful in demonstrating the importance of some variables for economic development, | ||
- | |||
- | Many authors have attempted to establish a reliable relationship between greater openness and higher growth. | ||
- | |||
- | > In particular the studies were identifying the negative effects of macroeconomic imbalances, instability and geographic location and misattributing them to trade restrictions. ---p34 | ||
- | |||
- | Their conclusions were not, therefore, supported by the data. It should also be noted that research has focused on openness rather than liberalisation. | ||
- | |||
- | Certainly, the bullishness of voices like the IMF in assuming an established relationship between liberalisation and growth cannot be supported by empirical evidence (but then international trade is not within the IMF's remit, so there is no reason that it //should// understand trade policy). | ||
- | |||
- | ===== Policy Implications ===== | ||
- | |||
- | On the right, claims that forthright unilateral liberalisation by developing countries will lead to welfare gains and economic growth are not supported by empirical evidence and often run contrary to historical experience. | ||
- | |||
- | On the left, a resistance to all calls for reform and an attempt to seek a complete answer to developing countries' | ||
- | |||
- | Many in the left interpret the right' | ||
- | |||
- | Alan Winters, Director of the Development Research Group at the World Bank: | ||
- | |||
- | > "the application of second-best economics [ie activist trade policy] needs first-best economists, not its usual complement of third- and fourth-raters." | ||
- | |||
- | In the authors' | ||
- | |||
- | The historical evidence that activist trade policy has almost always been used during the " | ||
- | |||
- | ====== The Need for a Development Round ====== | ||
- | |||
- | ===== Developing Countries and World Trade ===== | ||
- | |||
- | The General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) came into force in 1948 between 23 developed countries. | ||
- | |||
- | At its inception, the needs of developing countries were not considered. | ||
- | * products of interest to them (agricultural products and textiles) had already been excluded from the agenda | ||
- | * their markets were not of particular value to the developed countries (who were more interested in other developed markets), so they had little bargaining power | ||
- | * developing countries obtained exemptions from GATT rules: [[http:// | ||
- | * many countries including China, Brazil and India were still pursuing import substitution policies, and therefore had little interest in multilateral tariff reduction. | ||
- | |||
- | Agriculture and textiles were covered by separate agreements, whose provisions were starkly different to those of the GATT. Under the Multifibre Arrangement (MFA) developing countries bargained bilaterally for textiles quotas. | ||
- | |||
- | In the 1980s, many developing countries began to take a more active role in trade negotiations, | ||
- | * the increasing importance of exports of the East Asian economies lead to calls for them to stop 'free riding' | ||
- | * interest in the newly industrialised countries' | ||
- | * many developing countries were beginning to turn away from import substitution and take more interest in export-lead strategies | ||
- | |||
- | The Uruguay Round marked a significant expansion in the trade-related agenda, including the following areas for the first time: | ||
- | * trade in services (GATS) | ||
- | * intellectual property (TRIPS) | ||
- | * investment (TRIMs) | ||
- | |||
- | These issues were all of interest primarily to developed countries, although their offensive interests were now both developed and developing markets. | ||
- | |||
- | As the Uruguay Round was nearing completion, many developing countries were convinced that it was in their interests to complete because of the ambitious predictions of welfare gains made by international institutions: | ||
- | * the World Bank and US Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development predicted gains of approximately $200 billion per year | ||
- | * the GATT secretariat claimed gains would be at least $500 billion a year | ||
- | * the OECD predicted a total gain of $270 billion, of which $90 billion would accrue to developing countries. | ||
- | |||
- | In practice, these predictions proved to be over-optimistic, | ||
- | |||
- | > Indeed many of the poorest countries in the world will actually be worst off as a result of the round. | ||
- | |||
- | Sub-Saharan Africa is estimated to have lost around $1.2 billion --- many of the net losers are amongst the poorest countries in the world. | ||
- | |||
- | One reason for the predictions' | ||
- | |||
- | > [A]fter the implementation of Uruguay Round commitments, | ||
- | |||
- | The commitments made by developing countries in the Uruguay Round were unprecedented, | ||
- | |||
- | Unsurprisingly, | ||
- | |||
- | ===== Unfinished Business from Uruguay ===== | ||
- | |||
- | Although Uruguay had laid the basis for the inclusion of agriculture within the GATT, the focus had been on converting non-tariff barriers to tariffs (tariffication). | ||
- | |||
- | > In 1986--8 farm subsidies were equivalent to 51 per cent of all OECD farm production, and fourteen years later, after the implementation of Uruguay commitments... they still accounted for 48 per cent[.] ---p50 | ||
- | |||
- | Even in industrial goods there was scope for further reduction --- as noted earlier, tariffs on developed country exports remained many times higher than developing country exports (averaging 0.8 per cent compared to 3.4 per cent). | ||
- | * US tariffs on textiles and clothing: 15--35 per cent | ||
- | * Processed food: | ||
- | * Canada: 42 per cent | ||
- | * Japan: 65 per cent | ||
- | * EU: 24 per cent | ||
- | * Compared with least processed food products: | ||
- | * Canada: 3 per cent | ||
- | * Japan: 35 per cent | ||
- | * EU: 15 per cent | ||
- | |||
- | This type of tariff escalation discourages basic processing operations by creating enormous effective tariffs on value adding, and are acutely anti-development. | ||
- | |||
- | ===== New Areas of Importance ===== | ||
- | |||
- | Experience with the new areas of coverage illustrated that the agenda had been highly biased towards developed countries. | ||
- | |||
- | ====== What Has Doha Achieved? ====== | ||
- | |||
- | The Doha Round began in 2001 with the Doha Declaration laying out an ambitious developmental work programme ahead. | ||
- | |||
- | The failure to make progress and strong feelings that the US had reneged on the Doha Declaration and its earlier commitments were exacerbated by the negative public reaction to US-WTO attempts to use TRIPS provisions to prevent African governments from sourcing cheap generic drugs to combat the AIDS pandemic. | ||
- | |||
- | > In 2001, rich countries provided subsidies to their farmers which amounted to six times the amount of their development aid, respectively $311 billion and $55 billion... The African countries' | ||
- | |||
- | One consequence was the formation of unprecedentedly strong negotiating blocs amongst developing WTO members: the G20 leading negotiations on agriculture, | ||
- | |||
- | In mid-2004, the EU and US were ready to make limited concessions in the hope of salvaging the round, and all Singapore Issues apart from trade facilitation were dropped: the round would focus on core issues in agriculture, | ||
- | |||
- | ====== Founding Principles: The Basis of a Fair Agreement ====== | ||
- | |||
- | The concept of a " | ||
- | |||
- | The concept of a " | ||
- | |||
- | The authors propose four criteria by which to judge a development round: | ||
- | |||
- | > * Any agreement should be assessed in terms of its impact on development; | ||
- | > * Any agreement should be fair. | ||
- | > * Any agreement should be arrived at fairly. | ||
- | > * The agenda should be limited to trade-related and development-friendly issues. | ||
- | |||
- | ===== Impact Assessment ===== | ||
- | |||
- | Present and historical negotiations have not been lead by impact assessment. | ||
- | |||
- | The WTO Secretariat should take on the function of providing impact assessments of proposals before they are negotiated, to determine whether they are development-friendly. | ||
- | |||
- | This assessment cannot be based on neoclassical models, which are pathologically ill-suited to developing economies: | ||
- | * the assumption of **full employment** is inappropriate, | ||
- | * **adjustment costs** should be assumed non-zero and quantified | ||
- | * **risk and uncertainty** must be assumed non-zero and their effects taken into account: there are first-order welfare effects arising from risk in developing countries, for instance a quota (whilst inefficient in a risk-free environment) may be superior to a tariff because it will reduce price uncertainty (provided there is little domestic volatility) | ||
- | * analysis should take into account **pre-existing distortions**, | ||
- | * **global general equilibrium** must be considered, ie the effect that policies such as agricultural subsidies in large producers (the US and EU) have on world prices (these can only be safely ignored for small producers) | ||
- | * features of developing countries that are different to the developed economies for which most models have been built: | ||
- | * higher unemployment | ||
- | * higher adjustment costs | ||
- | * weaker safety nets | ||
- | * poorer risk markets | ||
- | * the cost of addressing any inequality generated by liberalisation, | ||
- | |||
- | The importance of adjustment costs also implies that WTO members should avoid bilateral agreements on the way to multilateral agreements, as these are likely to create short-term trade diversion. | ||
- | |||
- | WTO members also need to be honest about the fact that some provisions are redistributive rather than good, individually, | ||
- | |||
- | Intellectual property rights are distinct. | ||
- | |||
- | ===== Any Agreement Should Be Fair ===== | ||
- | |||
- | The authors do not attempt to justify why a development agreement should be fair. There does seem to be a growing international consensus, in rhetoric at least, that it should. | ||
- | |||
- | Opponents of the principle argue that trade negotiations are voluntary, and therefore beneficial for all --- if developing countries lost out from participation in the WTO, they would leave. | ||
- | * the threat of withholding aid is a powerful lever through which developed countries can gain compliance from developing countries | ||
- | * developing countries may benefit from the "rule of law" that the WTO provides without that law being fair (unfair law being better than total lawlessness) | ||
- | * it may be rational for an individual country to remain a part of the WTO even if it would be rational for the same country, as part of a larger bloc, to withdraw/ | ||
- | |||
- | It should be noted that, to the extent that countries are different, an agreement that applies uniformly to all countries may affect each country differently --- it will not necessarily be fair. For this reason, it is important to adopt the following principle: | ||
- | |||
- | > Any agreement that differentially hurts developing countries more or benefits the developed countries more... should be presumptively viewed as unfair... any reform [should] be // | ||
- | |||
- | One key problem with this criterion is that agricultural subsidies pose massive costs for developed countries, so their elimination is likely to benefit the developed economies more than others. | ||
- | |||
- | Fairness also requires that two failures of the dispute settlement system be rectified: | ||
- | * the WTO system needs an equivalent of legal aid to cover the cost of disputes for developing countries --- whilst imperfect this would go some way to address the problem that developing countries can often not afford to bring disputes, whereas the costs are trivial for larger countries | ||
- | * sanctions permitted to redress wrongdoing are crippling when imposed by large economies and trivial when imposed by small ones --- no solution is proposed at this point in the text (see later) but it is noted that global action against a large economy can be effective, as when the world responded as a bloc to increased protection of the US steel industry, forcing America to back down. | ||
- | |||
- | > The EC, Japan and the US were complainants in almost half (143 of 305) of all bilateral disputes... between 1995 and 2002. By contrast the 49 members classified by the UN as Less [sic] Developed Countries did not bring a single challenge in that period. | ||
- | |||
- | A further difficulty in the application of fairness is whether to view WTO agreements in isolation from the actions of other multilateral institutions (asking that WTO agreements, in isolation, be " | ||
- | |||
- | In the South, there is a tendency to view such multi-pronged attack as coordinated. | ||
- | |||
- | > The high interest rates, tax policies, and trade liberalisation policies demanded by the IMF do exacerbate the adverse effects on developing countries of whatever trade liberalisation measures they agree to within the WTO. The two cannot be seen isolation. | ||
- | |||
- | ===== Any Agreement Should Be Arrived At Fairly ===== | ||
- | |||
- | Procedural fairness is particularly important when there is disagreement about exactly what constitutes a fair agreement. | ||
- | |||
- | ===== Scope of the WTO's Mandate ===== | ||
- | |||
- | In the Uruguay Round, the scope of the WTO's operations grew alarmingly. | ||
- | * developing countries have limited capacity to analyse and negotiate a broad range of issues | ||
- | * experience with Singapore Issues suggest that a broad scope can make agreement more difficult | ||
- | * increased scope permits developed countries to apply their disproportionate bargaining power to arbitrary new issues (for instance, it would have been impossible for the US-EU to have negotiated a TRIPS-like treaty with as many other countries outside of the WTO). | ||
- | |||
- | A ' | ||
- | * relevance to trade flows | ||
- | * development-friendliness, | ||
- | * the existence of a rationale for collective action. | ||
- | |||
- | > [M]odern trade agreements have been extended into areas which intrude into national sovereignty with no justification based on the need for collective action and without clearly identified and fairly distributed global benefits. | ||
- | |||
- | ====== Special Treatment for Developing Countries ====== | ||
- | |||
- | One of the most important challenges for a development round is to develop a system that treats less developed economies differently to more developed economies, whilst remaining predictable, | ||
- | * financial support with WTO participation | ||
- | * aid to improve capacity to take advantage of trading opportunities | ||
- | * exemptions from agreements or delays in the date in which they come into force | ||
- | * permission for developed countries to provide favourable market access to developing countries (against MFN) | ||
- | |||
- | SDT is controversial. | ||
- | * it breaks the principle of reciprocity on which the WTO is based | ||
- | * according to neoliberal theory, protectionism that SDT encourages is inefficient and bad for developing countries themselves: they'd be better off if forced to liberalise completely (the problems with neoliberal assumptions was discussed in chapter 2) | ||
- | |||
- | |||
- | ===== SDT in Doha ===== | ||
- | |||
- | SDT has always been an important demand of the developing countries in Doha, with the G33 its main proponent. | ||
- | |||
- | The danger of the RFF approach is that it would reduce the participation of the RFF countries in the round --- indeed, its intention was surely to overcome opposition to developed country proposals by the RFF countries by reducing their incentive to get involved. | ||
- | |||
- | More importantly, | ||
- | |||
- | ===== Doha Market Access Proposal ===== | ||
- | |||
- | In order to capture some of these gains, the authors set out a Doha market access proposal (MAP). | ||
- | |||
- | The principle is of a rules-based system based on objective criteria that is nevertheless progressive. | ||
- | * it involves significant liberalisation (much more than the RFF approach) | ||
- | * rules of origin would reduce the value of this liberalisation less than under other preferential schemes, because inputs would often come from other qualifying countries | ||
- | * in particular, it involves significant South-South liberalisation, | ||
- | * obligations are distributed progressively, | ||
- | * countries retain the ability to manage major import threats (from larger or richer countries), so they can pursue infant industry or avoid heavy adjustment costs of removing barriers until appropriate safety nets are in place | ||
- | * MAP is consistent with the existing MFN system: existing MFN tariffs remain in all trading relations not affected by MAP, and can be subject to negotiated reduction as usual (it should be noted that the scheme does reduce the bargaining power of poorer countries in future rounds, but on the other hand by removing preferences between classes of developing countries, it destroys the incentive for some developing countries to oppose rich-country liberalisation for fear of preference erosion((Actually, | ||
- | * it creates well-defined obligations to replace discretionary preferential schemes, giving commitments greater certainty and value. | ||
- | * it is simple, whilst effectively differentiating: | ||
- | |||
- | Although not discussed explicitly, details such as adjustment periods, provisions for specific sectors and many other complexities would have to be negotiated as part of this overarching policy. | ||
- | |||
- | ===== SDT in Rules ===== | ||
- | |||
- | There is now wide recognition that WTO " | ||
- | |||
- | Developing countries should demand exemptions from such multilateral rules, including in proposed Doha agreements on competition and investment. | ||
- | |||
- | > Compulsory commitments should not be made in areas where the purported gains are controversial and where implementation and opportunity costs are high. And where the gains are certain and the costs are low for developing countries (such as allegedly in efforts to liberalise some aspects of FDI regulations), | ||
- | |||
- | > A blanket proscription against government subsidies to technology (industrial policies) is likely to have an adverse effect on developing countries and, indeed, it is likely in practice to be unfair: the United States conducts its industrial policy largely through the military, which supports a wide variety of technological developments that eventually have important civilian applications. | ||
- | |||
- | ====== Priorities for a Development Round ====== | ||
- | |||
- | > The problem, of course, is that political globalisation has not kept pace with economic globalisation: | ||
- | |||
- | The current focus of Doha, on areas of dubious benefit to developing countries and neglecting important developmental areas, is inappropriate for a development round, and ignores the historical context in which developed countries have accrued far greater benefits from the multilateral system than the poor. There is an important asymmetry of power in the negotiations: | ||
- | |||
- | The authors' | ||
- | * the market access proposal detailed in the previous chapter | ||
- | * developed countries commit to eliminate all agricultural subsidies (production as well as export) | ||
- | * market access commitments must not be undermined by restrictive rules of origin and other barriers | ||
- | |||
- | In other words, reciprocity should not be the basis of negotiations. | ||
- | |||
- | The authors present further, less central, proposals: | ||
- | * sharp reduction in tariff peaks | ||
- | * elimination of tariff escalation | ||
- | * liberalisation in developed countries should focus on priority products, especially agricultural commodities and textiles | ||
- | * services liberalisation should focus on labour-intensive areas such as maritime and construction | ||
- | * low-skilled labour mobility schemes, particularly temporary migration of unskilled workers | ||
- | * restriction of the non-tariff barriers that developed countries have developed as an alternative to tariffs | ||
- | |||
- | The chapter contains a detailed table of further proposals (table 7.1, p112--4), which itself summarises the analysis presented in the appendices. | ||
- | * non-tariff barriers: | ||
- | * eliminate dumping duties and replace with a single fair competition regime | ||
- | * permit developing countries to subsidise infant industries | ||
- | * permit developing countries to subsidise high interest rates | ||
- | * development: | ||
- | * developing countries permitted to use measures in their development interest even when restricted for developed countries, especially measures for poor farmers | ||
- | * IP: | ||
- | * new pro-generic drug policy | ||
- | * greater scope for compulsory licensing | ||
- | * higher novelty standards for patenting | ||
- | * greater restrictions on biopiracy (patenting traditional medicines) | ||
- | * tax: | ||
- | * restriction of subsidies and tax concessions for foreign firms, to prevent " | ||
- | * arms: | ||
- | * prohibition of arms sales | ||
- | * criminalisation of bribery | ||
- | * elimination of secret bank accounts | ||
- | * commitment to repatriate corrupt funds | ||
- | * dispute resolution: | ||
- | * greater technical and financial assistance for developing countries | ||
- | * multilateral enforcement (non-injured parties can also retaliate against an offending member) | ||
- | * monetisation of sanctions (developing countries can sell the right to sanction to other members for whom the sanction would be more valuable, eg if Nicaragua won a dispute against the US, it could sell the right to impose duties to China or the EU) | ||
- | * institutional reform | ||
- | * creation of evaluation unit within the WTO to assess likely impact of measures on developing countries | ||
- | * greater transparency (elimination of the Green Room, etc) | ||
- | |||
- | ====== How to Open Up Markets ====== | ||
- | |||
- | ===== Services (including Labour Mobility) ===== | ||
- | |||
- | The basic rationale for trade liberalisation is to increase economies of scale and improve efficiency in the allocation of resources. | ||
- | |||
- | Notwithstanding this, liberalisation of unskilled labour has lagged far behind the liberalisation of goods and services generally. | ||
- | |||
- | In order to maximise the development benefit of migrant labour, governments (and potentially the WTO) can get involved in improving systems of remittances to make the remittance of wages cheaper, safer and more convenient (at present a large portion of remittances flow through informal channels). | ||
- | |||
- | There are further GATS sectors that are of particular interest to developing countries in modes 1 and 2 (the expansion of offshore outsourcing has already lead to rapid growth in some of these sectors): | ||
- | * business services | ||
- | * ICT | ||
- | * health | ||
- | * education | ||
- | * audiovisual services | ||
- | |||
- | There are also non-market access reforms that could provide development benefits. | ||
- | |||
- | A similar situation exists in mode 3 liberalisation --- many developing countries have unilaterally liberalised FDI rules, but a WTO agreement limiting the negative effects of competition between governments to provide the most attractive financial incentives to foreign investors could increase the development benefits of this liberalisation. | ||
- | |||
- | A final opportunity for improvement exists to provide greater scope for governments to adopt appropriate social policy. | ||
- | |||
- | ===== Agriculture ===== | ||
- | |||
- | Chapter 3 discussed the high levels of agricultural protection in the OECD and the negative effects on developing country production. | ||
- | - Begin by reducing border protection (tariffs and export subsidies), with reduction most rapid on goods produced primarily in developing countries and those consumed primarily in developed countries (eg sugar, tropical products, cotton). | ||
- | - Production subsidies on price-sensitive necessities consumed widely in developing countries should be reduced gradually, with part of the savings in subsidy budgets committed to developing countries to cover adjustment costs (North Africa, Sub-Saharan Africa and Latin America (except Brazil, Argentina, Mexico) rely on imports of grains and oilseeds subsidised in the OECD). | ||
- | - Domestic support should switch to payment systems that do not encourage production (such as land-based payments). | ||
- | |||
- | ===== Industrial Goods ===== | ||
- | |||
- | Developing country interests have been neglected in previous tariff liberalisation, | ||
- | * tariff peaks on products of interest to developing countries, and | ||
- | * tariff escalation (higher tariffs on more-processed goods) | ||
- | |||
- | > For example, in 2001, clothes and shoes accounted for only 6.5 per cent of US imports in value terms but they brought nearly half of the $20 billion of US tariff revenue. | ||
- | |||
- | In analysing the impact of escalation, it is important to calculate the effective tariff rate on value adding; analysis based only on nominal rates will not reveal the true development impact. | ||
- | |||
- | Additionally, | ||
- | |||
- | ===== Non-tariff Barriers ===== | ||
- | |||
- | Legal commitments to liberalise do not eliminate protectionist sentiment or the " | ||
- | * **dumping duties** can be applied where a foreign exporter is (allegedly) selling below cost | ||
- | * **countervailing duties** can be applied to counteract the effects of a subsidy received by a foreign exporter | ||
- | * **safeguards** can be applied temporarily to protect a domestic industry from a surge in imports, and | ||
- | * **safety standards** can be applied to protect food security, prevent the movement of pests, etc. | ||
- | |||
- | The general problem is that non-tariff barriers can be applied too easily by developed countries: | ||
- | * in some cases (particularly dumping), the rules are too permissive, and | ||
- | * more generally, the procedures are unable to prevent consistent misuse, especially by large rich countries. | ||
- | |||
- | America' | ||
- | * in some cases, the initially high duty is sufficient to drive the exporting firm out of business | ||
- | * the uncertainty in the duty to be paid will discourage importing firms from using that supplier | ||
- | |||
- | The calculation of " | ||
- | |||
- | Safeguards are overused by the United States and probably underused by developing countries. | ||
- | |||
- | > If the richest country in the world, the United States, with a strong safety net, relatively high employment level, etc, has to resort to safety measures to protect itself against a surge of imports, how much more justified are developing countries in imposing such measures. | ||
- | |||
- | Clearer standards are required at the international level to determine when safeguards can be applied, and these should include SDT for developing countries. | ||
- | |||
- | Reform requires three components: | ||
- | * the adoption of **national treatment** in this area: for instance, in the US, antitrust law protects domestic firms from one another, but the threshold for anti-competitive practices are far higher than that applied for foreign firms | ||
- | * the creation of an **international tribunal as the //first// court**: an international panel of experts would have to endorse a plaintiff' | ||
- | * legislation and practices should be **reviewed** by the secretariat to determine whether they are fair and non-discriminatory, | ||
- | |||
- | The determination of what constitutes a subsidy also requires clarification to rectify current problems: | ||
- | * richer countries use " | ||
- | * subsidies on credit applied to counteract IMF measures forcing developing countries to raise interest rates should not be considered a subsidy | ||
- | * the fair auction of privatised assets should be considered to extinguish any subsidy previously received (similar to the sale of assets in a bankruptcy auction), but when government effectively gives away state assets then the subsidy is not extinguished (this could have the side-benefit of encouraging more honest privatisations) | ||
- | |||
- | ====== Priorities Behind the Border ====== | ||
- | |||
- | Development-friendly behind-the-border measures that should be included in a Doha agreement: | ||
- | * **Restrictions on tax and incentive competition**, | ||
- | - disclosure/ | ||
- | - cooperation between governments | ||
- | - enforceable international rules | ||
- | * **Anti-corruption policies** could adopt rules laid out in, for example, America' | ||
- | * full disclosure of payments made to foreign companies | ||
- | * agreement that only disclosed payments can be tax-deductible | ||
- | * commitment to repatriate stolen funds | ||
- | * restrictions on sources of illicit revenue, especially those used to finance armed insurrections | ||
- | * agreement banning bank account secrecy | ||
- | * strong restrictions on arms sales, especially small arms | ||
- | * **Environmental policy**: | ||
- | * the recent " | ||
- | * WTO law should support members' | ||
- | * developing countries should be given assistance in abandoning subsidies on fossil-fuel-derived energy | ||
- | * Part of the original motivation for the establishment of the GATT was to ensure a **cooperative response to crises**, despite the various (rarely used) safeguards that the WTO agreements contain for the use of trade policy during crises. | ||
- | * an international panel within the WTO could make recommendations in such cases. | ||
- | * the Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures (SCM) should be clarified to ensure that it does not prohibit the provision of trade finance during crises (which could currently be considered a subsidy) | ||
- | * multilateral mechanisms to provide trade finance, especially during crises, could be improved | ||
- | * Developing countries should be given greater assistance to address adjustment and implementation costs. | ||
- | |||
- | ====== What Should Not Be on the Agenda ====== | ||
- | |||
- | > The fact that the US and EU put [the Singapore Issues] on the agenda and continued to push them for so long within the so-called Development Round is of concern: were they merely bargaining chips? | ||
- | |||
- | ===== Intellectual Property ===== | ||
- | |||
- | The authors believe that the balance of intellectual property rights in the US and embodied within TRIPS favours rights holders more than is beneficial for economic efficiency and development. | ||
- | |||
- | There are many development dangers from IP law that is too strong: | ||
- | * weak patent laws are required to safeguard public health (most developed countries have at one time used laws permitting generic drug manufacture on public health grounds) | ||
- | * the difference between marginal cost of production and price can be viewed as a tax to finance research: principles of equity demand that the poorest consumers not be taxed in this way, so the international community needs an alternative mechanism for financing this activity | ||
- | |||
- | > Before NAFTA, Canada routinely granted compulsory licenses on pharmaceutical products for the purpose of reducing health costs through widely available generic drugs. | ||
- | |||
- | The authors believe that //TRIPS causes such comprehensive harm that it should be rolled back// | ||
- | |||
- | If TRIPS is not to be eliminated, then it needs to be revised in various areas, and developing countries need further support to fully exploit its provisions. | ||
- | * TRIPS permits governments to authorise manufacturers to produce drugs without the consent of the patent owner: developing countries need assistance in creating administrative procedures to do so that are immune from (expensive) legal challenges by the drug companies ("the median cost of US patent litigation in 1998 was $1.2 million for each party." | ||
- | * TRIPS should be extended to permit compulsory licensing beyond national emergencies to " | ||
- | * [[http:// | ||
- | * Pursuant to [[http:// | ||
- | * Any revision to current WTO IP law should make it as quick and easy as possible for generic drugs to enter the market on the expiration of a patent (the US has been attempting to make it more difficult through recent bilateral agreements) | ||
- | * [[http:// | ||
- | |||
- | ===== Competition ===== | ||
- | |||
- | Discussion in Doha has centred more on improving access of developed country firms into developing markets than on making markets more competitive or improving access by developing country firms into developed markets. | ||
- | * national treatment: either dumping duties or antitrust legislation would need revision, to ensure the same standards apply to both foreign and domestic firms | ||
- | * better application of antitrust law across jurisdictions: | ||
- | * domestic antitrust regulators should look at the effects on foreign markets | ||
- | * foreign consumers should have the right to take action | ||
- | * cross-border class action suits should be enabled so that consumers in multiple jurisdictions can impose sanctions enforceable in the corporation' | ||
- | * consumers and governments should be able to take action (including class action) against international cartels, including those involving governments or government sanctions (ie OPEC) | ||
- | * development policies such as affirmative action and preferences for small businesses should be permitted, even when they have a differential impact on foreign firms | ||
- | |||
- | ===== Investment ===== | ||
- | |||
- | According to the conservatism principle, investment should not be part of a WTO trade agreement. | ||
- | * environmental restrictions affect trade: the EU restricts carbon emissions whilst the US does not, giving American firms a cost advantage | ||
- | * labour restrictions affect trade: countries with anti-union laws enable firms to depress wages, creating a cost advantage | ||
- | * there is no real evidence that investment agreements increase investments (all major studies have found weak or no evidence that the 2000 bilateral agreements signed by 2001 increased investment) | ||
- | * unilateral investment liberalisation is proceeding rapidly; this enables tailoring appropriate to local circumstances | ||
- | * liberalising the movement of capital is less important for economic efficiency than the movement of workers, particularly unskilled labour | ||
- | * there is a strong case that liberalising the movement of capital lowers global economic efficiency, and that liberalisation causes economic instability such as the recent crises in LA and in East Asia in the late 1990s | ||
- | * multilateral investment mechanisms already exist, such as the Multilateral Investment Guarantee Agency (MIGA) | ||
- | |||
- | If an agreement were to be negotiated, the most important development issue would to prevent a "race to the bottom", | ||
- | * tax incentives | ||
- | * labour standards, or | ||
- | * environmental standards | ||
- | |||
- | as a means of attracting foreign investment. | ||
- | |||
- | ===== Financial Services ===== | ||
- | |||
- | Previous services negotiations had a considerable focus on financial services, which should be re-examined. | ||
- | |||
- | > In at least some developing countries there are concerns that the purchase of local banks by foreign banks has reduced the flow of credit to small and medium-sized domestic enterprises, | ||
- | |||
- | ===== Regulatory Interventions ===== | ||
- | |||
- | Developing countries are concerned that new trade agreements will create additional barriers to the entry of their goods, particularly "blue tariffs" | ||
- | * when the global community is affected, such as in the Shrimp-Turtle case: not forcing firms to bear the cost of environmental degradation amounts to a subsidy | ||
- | * human rights violations such as forced or child labour, or land seized from indigenous peoples: the global community should not encourage such actions by permitting firms to benefit from a consequential cost advantage | ||
- | * actions that unfairly affect the cost of production, such as restrictions on collective bargaining that reduce wages | ||
- | |||
- | Whilst some argue that these would be better addressed through a channel other than a trade agreement, in reality there are few other options. | ||
- | |||
- | ===== Exchange Rate Manipulation ===== | ||
- | |||
- | The US has recently attacked China for allegedly manipulating its exchange rate. The situation is so complex that in almost all cases it is impossible to definitively determine whether this is truly a deliberate government policy. | ||
- | |||
- | |||
- | ====== Joining the Trading System ====== | ||
- | |||
- | [[http:// | ||
- | * greater binding coverage than existing members (some LDCs have accepted greater binding coverage than Australia, a developed member) | ||
- | * lower bound rates (LDCs have bound at much lower maximum rates than the US) | ||
- | * waiver of SDT, including shorter transition times on the TBT, SPS and customs valuation agreements, as well as TRIPS, including immediately eliminating "the use of affordable new generic drugs" | ||
- | * China had to accept an extraordinary right of other members to use safeguards against it (beyond GATT [[http:// | ||
- | * some LDCs have bound export subsidies at zero (far beyond many developed countries' | ||
- | |||
- | > It seems strange that the WTO's developed country members should force acceding countries, particularly small and poor countries like Cambodia and Nepal, into such strong concessions. | ||
- | |||
- | The WTO urgently needs to implement the December 2002 General Council decision to make accession more transparent, | ||
- | |||
- | Whilst Doha has floundered, the US has been aggressively pursuing bilateral treaties. | ||
- | * they // | ||
- | * the US has greater power in these negotiations, | ||
- | |||
- | As discussed, there are large potential gains from the liberalisation of South-South trade. | ||
- | |||
- | ====== Institutional Reforms ====== | ||
- | |||
- | > The result [of secretive trade negotiations without parliamentary oversight] is agreements, like Chapter 11 of the NAFTA... or the TRIPS Agreement, which contain provisions that would probably never have been accepted by a democratic parliament with open discussion in a deliberative process. ---p167 | ||
- | |||
- | Reform in the way in which trade negotiations are conducted and the WTO is structured is urgent. | ||
- | * trade ministers are no longer adequate representatives of a country' | ||
- | * environmental ministers must meet (not be represented by trade ministers) to discuss the environmental impact of provisions | ||
- | * health and science ministers must be involved if trade institutions are going to continue to discuss intellectual property | ||
- | * although the Green Room approach has been formally abolished, there is no structured, agreed replacement and in effect elements of its process continue --- these should be replaced with an agreed structure to maintain representativeness, | ||
- | * a new (secretarial) body or bodies should be created within the WTO to: | ||
- | * supply impact assessments to developing countries, to mitigate their informational disadvantage | ||
- | * assess whether proposed bilateral trade agreements are consistent with the principle that trade diversion should be limited and less than trade creation | ||
- | * assess countries in crisis and approve safeguard and other emergency measures | ||
- | * assistance provided through the WTO system should be reassessed: | ||
- | * technical assistance with implementation will continue to be needed | ||
- | * adjustment costs are not merely institutional but in many developing countries sizeable additional financial assistance will be required | ||
- | * legal assistance will be required to supplement an overhaul of dispute settlement to make it fairer to developing countries | ||
- | |||
- | |||
- | ====== Trade Liberalisation and the Costs of Adjustment ====== | ||
- | |||
- | This chapter presents more supporting empirical information than previous chapters. | ||
- | |||
- | Understanding of adjustment costs is important because: | ||
- | * the Development Round' | ||
- | * opposition to liberalisation often comes from groups who will face the largest costs: compensating these groups may be necessary to enable liberalisation | ||
- | |||
- | Liberalisation brings various different types of cost: | ||
- | * workers and capital in previously protected industries become unemployed in the short run | ||
- | * government or workers face adaptation costs, such as training, benefits, search costs | ||
- | * government bears implementation and enforcement costs, which are particularly high in the case of Singapore issues (in many cases the cost of implementation may be higher than the country' | ||
- | * investment is required to take advantage of new opportunities: | ||
- | * by government: infrastructure such as transport and standards and conformance institutions | ||
- | * by firms: new facilities and technologies | ||
- | * costs associated with redistribution between factors, such as compensation by government (liberalisation usually leads factor prices to move towards international prices) | ||
- | * reduction in tariff revenues may force governments to implement new tax regimes (notoriously difficult in developing economies, and likely also to distort the economy and undermine growth) or else cut public expenditure: | ||
- | * increased exposure to risk, for instance when quotas are tariffised | ||
- | |||
- | Adjustment costs disproportionately impact developing countries, because: | ||
- | * their **export industries are undiversified** (often reliant on one or two commodities) and therefore vulnerable to policy shocks | ||
- | * they require **large institutional changes** to comply with international standards (whereas developed countries are already closer) | ||
- | * world trade is **most distorted in industries important for developing countries**, | ||
- | * they have the world' | ||
- | |||
- | Studies quantifying adjustment costs in developed countries find that costs accrue mainly to workers, and that they are small compared with consumer benefits (eg Baldwin, Mutti and Richardson (1980) analyse a 50 per cent cut in US tariffs and find 90 per cent of costs are borne by laid-off workers (the remainder by capital stock) but that total costs are only 4 per cent of total gains --- other studies give similar results). | ||
- | |||
- | > For example, liberalisation of the cashew market in Mozambique in the late 1990s led to the loss of 85 per cent of the workforce employed in the local processed-cashew industry. | ||
- | |||
- | Costs in developing countries are exacerbated by: | ||
- | * weak access to credit | ||
- | * firms can't finance adjustment in production | ||
- | * workers can't afford retraining or their own search for new employment | ||
- | * high unemployment: | ||
- | * low education: studies show that costs are lower for better educated (therefore more mobile) workers | ||
- | * reduction in tariff preferences for the poorest countries | ||
- | |||
- | The authors present a range of evidence suggesting that the benefits of non-reciprocal tariff preferences (both GSP and especially LDC schemes such as EBA and AGOA) are small, and more than offset by the likely benefits from reductions in MFN tariffs, especially by developing countries who don't have GSP schemes but do currently have higher tariffs than developed countries. | ||
- | |||
- | > In a sense the GSP only partially compensates for the discrimination by developed countries against the goods produced by developing countries. ---p183 | ||
- | |||
- | Adjustment costs vary not only by country but between different vulnerable groups within each country. | ||
- | * unemployment | ||
- | * factor prices, and | ||
- | * goods prices | ||
- | |||
- | Fiscal effects also vary a lot between countries. | ||
- | |||
- | On the basis of proper per-country analysis, assistance must be provided to governments to improve safety nets for workers and to improve credit markets for firms (if necessary to counteract misguided IMF policy artificially inflating interest rates). | ||
- | |||
- | ====== Appendices ====== | ||
- | |||
- | Two appendices contain empirical reviews of market access and Singapore issues. | ||
- | |||
- | ====== Selected Bibliography ====== | ||
- | |||
- | The following works are mentioned in this abridgement: | ||
- | |||
- | * **Baldwin**, | ||
- | * **Brenton**, | ||
- | * **Grynberg**, | ||
- | * **Kuznets**, | ||
- | * **Lewis**, W A, 1955, //The Theory of Economic Growth//, London: George Allen & Unwin | ||
- | * **Samuelson**, | ||
- | * **Rodrik**, Dani, 2004, " |